Book Summary and Review
Most of you know that my fascination with money has dealt
mostly with the problems of many in the developing world. These include issues
such as lack of access to capital and financing (microfinance seeks to address
this), lack of foreign investment, Dutch disease,
safety/security issues and poverty caused or aggravated by inflation and
hyperinflation, etc. I’ve been intrigued by examples of micro-economies,
microlending, microsavings, and alternative currencies (The Future of Money, Do-It-Yourself Currencies, World of Good Markets, The Future of Barter, Local Exchange Trading Systems, Community Currencies in the U.S.).
But the truth of it is that money is facing problems the entire world round.
And by the way, what is money? Have you ever thought of that?
I think about what money is awhile. I’ve been reading “The
End of Money” by David Wolman after hearing Wolman speak, and I’ve been
pondering greatly this issue of money. When you ask people about what sets
humans apart from other animals, they will usually mention music or art or high
level of intelligence or highly complex language. But rarely do people say
money. However, we’re the only animal that I know of that uses money (of
course, some might say money is a by-product of our intelligence). But that
still doesn’t answer what it is. What is it?
From the pre-money or early-money days when money took the
form of whale teeth, feathers, shells, trinkets, butter, salt, tobacco,
anything that had value (or didn’t as is seen the example of stone monuments
used on the Micronesian Island of Yap), there were always problems. First, not
all feathers are alike. Secondly, there might be a limited supply of whale
teeth (supply is something that I’ll come back to). Third, some of these items
decay. Fourth, some of the items just didn’t have any intrinsic value and could
become worthless of people didn’t believe in their value. So coins were finally
born in the Greek kingdom of Lydia, 2600
years ago.
Coins were something that could be made to be all alike,
whose supply could be controlled (assuming it was made from a substance found
in sufficient quantities), take a long time to decay if made from good
material, and have intrinsic value if made from material people saw as
valuable. Coins are fungible (meaning you can interchange it or use it for a
variety of uses or purchases), and you can even put your face on it if you’re
the government.
Even though gold has no real intrinsic value, any more than
silver or bronze, people sure like it. And if people like something, it, in
some sense, it became infused with value. Additionally, it’s tough, malleable,
nonflammable, nonpoisonous, nonreactive, and just scarce enough to add to our
fascination with it. However gold coins became a problem, too, as its scarcity
became a hindrance to boosting it’s the money supply. Additionally, sometimes
people thought it was better to hoard and save your gold. One of the earliest
monetary “crashes” I heard of was the 16th century Spanish Empire
which plundered the silver mines of South America so much that there was an
oversupply of silver. This caused steep price increases that the purchasing
power of the silver dropped very quickly and the money became worthless.
Paper money (originally born as early as 800 AD in China and
first replacing coins during the 13th century Yuan Dynasty) was
finally reborn in 17th century Europe when people would bring gold
and jewelry to the goldsmith to fashion coins. The goldsmith would give you a
receipt to say he has your jewelry and that you’ll soon get your coins back.
Well, since the receipt represented a certain amount of gold, people began
using the receipts themselves to trade with others like the butcher for meat.
The goldsmiths quickly realized that people weren’t checking how many of these
notes they issued, and as long as no one checked, they could issue as many as
they wanted. David Wolman calls this the birth of modern banking. Ha ha!
Without going into the historical details, the next
evolution in money came in colonial America when people started issuing paper
money not backed by coins, but backed by a promise of the government to repay
in coins or something valuable in the future. Somewhat differently, in China a
version of this had happened in which the government hid the fact that the
paper money was not backed by coins. Here, it was not concealed.
So cash had arrived, and just like today, it was a
promissory note saying “We promise to pay you back in some form at some day in
the future, as long as that day is not today.” This is the strange thing about
money. Again, what is it? Well defining exactly what it was became harder and
hard which led to two more transformations.
In 1933, US President Roosevelt decided to consolidate the
country’s gold supply in an effort to build the economy during the Great
Depression. Then all the major economies sent representatives to a private
meeting in which they agreed to their money to the US dollar with a fixed
exchange rate that can only be changed by permission with the International
Monetary Fund (IMF). As part of the agreement, countries could exchange their
foreign reserves of US dollars for gold from the US.
In the early 1970s it was quite obvious that the US had no
ability to back all the foreign US dollars which was three times the amount of
gold held in reserve by the US. So the US President Richard Nixon, in August
1971, de-tethered gold from the US dollar. From that point on, the value of
gold in US dollars was now set by the market. And all currencies were allowed
to move up and down against each other as the market saw fit. However, goods
were still priced on the world market in USD and it was also agreed that oil
would be bought and sold in USD.
And so we arrive at the world of today, but that still begs
the question. What is money? Well, it seems like it’s nothing now. In fact
there are men who receive a lot of it to simply decide how much should be
created each year. Other men receive a lot of it to decide what should the
general interest rate be, and this changes the amount of effective money (since
credit increases people’s buying power). And it’s simply amazing to me that
people have such responsibility to make these decisions about some pieces of
papers whose scarcity makes it valuable and whose abundance makes it useful.
But what of people who don’t have money or have too little money. I wonder if
they’d like to see more money created and put in the system. Or what about
people who work full-time for too little money? I bet they would like to see
more money in the system. But how do you do this? More importantly, if money
really is nothing, why print it at all? If it’s just in our heads and belief
systems, why not work with digital money? Maybe in this way, people will see
that it’s just an arbitrary (though educationally informed) decision about how
much of it should be in the society.
The current problem is paper itself. We could be headed to
the next transformation—from paper to digital. It’s not a new prophesy; in
fact, it’s a recurring cry heard from people such as technologists, but there
are many barriers to moving to a cashless society.
There are the evangelical Christians with an apocalyptic
interpretation of Revelations. Many of these people feel that eliminating cash
is the last step toward the predicted mark of the beast according to the
interpretation. Other possible steps may have been the elimination of the gold
standard, establishment of the UN, barcodes, radio-emitting microchips, and
growing Wall Street banks. All of these things are seen as possibly heading to
some one-world order in which a person (the Antichrist) controls the economic
system of the world. According to this view, it is inevitable and money’s
destiny is digital. However, they don’t want to rush the end and the impending end-time
carnage.
There are the technologists. They argue against paper money
on two counts. One it’s a losing game. For example, one in every 1 pound bill
is counterfeit, and 40% of all UK-issued pennies are missing. A few years ago
the price of a penny peaked at 1.8 cents and a nickel (5 cents) cost 9 cents to
make. A nickel is now 6 cents to make and the price of a penny has come down.
But it is a problem when it cost more than what the money is worth to make it.
These problems increase (there are many statistics) from lost coinage to
monetary costs of coins to environmental costs of making coins including
pollution, acid rain, the use of water and cotton in production, etc. The US
Mint has manufactured 500 billion coins over the past generation, yet 200
billion of those coins have fallen out of circulation. Some people want to kill
just the US penny or the US nickel. Some want to kill all coins. Some don’t
want any money. Norway, Denmark, and
Sweden all removed all of their coins less than 0.50 of their currency. The
cost of money-making increases when you include ATMs, armoured cars, night
safes, transportation. This includes robberies, security, cash handling (annual
cost of cash-handling in Indonesia is $800 million).
This brings up the second reason technologists oppose it.
Cash supports illegal activities. It’s anonymous and virtually untraceable. It
encourages counterfeiting and robberies. It supports drug wars and money
launderers, gangsters and war lords. It encourages tax evasion (there is about
a $350 billion tax gap in the US between what should be taken in and what
actually is received). It encourages cash robberies. Every year around 800
Americans are killed in cash robberies, and there were more than 10,000 bank
robberies in 2009 and 2010 that would not have happened if there were no cash.
And the stories go on. Some people are just loyal to the
penny or to cash and don’t want to see it go. Some people see credit card
companies as predatory (understandably so) and prefer that people completely
tear up all credit cards and live on what they earn (of course there are
troubles with this—how do you pay for university studies for a family that does
not have the money?). Some people feel that when they physically hold money
they spend less money. In other words, as Wolman put it, if you walk into a
casino with $300 you know you might lose $300. But if you walk into a casino
with a credit card, you could lose your house. There are people who have an
emotional attachment to the physical feeling of money. They are called
tactilists.
Some people deplore the tracking of digital money that can
tell when and where you’ve spent your money and for what activities. They
prefer the anonymity of cash. Of course, so do criminals.
There are some who know cash penalizes the poor
disproportionately. The poor have little options for other forms of money such
as credit and bank accounts. For many people, because it is easier to spend
cash, the lack of banking hinders the ability to save. They often
disproportionately face risks associated with money such as security/safety
risks with cash. This is especially true in places where the money’s value is
low or dropping or when it is dropping extremely fast (hyperinflation). Some
people might have to spend multiple days on a bus to deliver money to a
grandmother in a rural town. That is lost time and money just due to travel.
Now through the advent of mobile money technologies, people can use cell phones
to send and receive money. Imagine saving 3 days of travel and your rural
grandmother receiving the money instantly. Imagine that now she can choose to
spend it at a shop or save it “in the phone.” Kenyan taxi drivers use the
mobile-money giant, M-Pesa, to load up their cell phone money accounts so they
don’t have to carry cash (just go into a store or any operator who will take
your cash and send money to your account through the phone). Wolman tells a second-hand
story o f a man in Kenya who put money on his phone when traveling through a
dangerous part of the city because he didn’t want cash on himself. When he
exited that part of the city he took out cash again at a nearby shop. Kenya’s
central bank has reported a drop in cash usage, and there were 13 million users
(half the adults in Kenya) after only 4 years of operation by M-Pesa.
So the stories continue. But whether physical money will
ever disappear is a bigger and longer prediction. People like physical money
and it is hard to part with tradition or inertia. Some people think Japan or
South Korea since they love technology and adopt new technology faster than in
the UK or the US. Others think it might be Sweden since there was a banker-led
campaign to do away with physical cash. We shall see. If or when any country
does it, it will still be some time in the future. But it’s quite interesting
to watch how it unfolds.
No comments:
Post a Comment